ºÝºÝߣs for the Academic Identities conference, 8-9th July, 2014.
In this paper we analyse ¡®academic labour¡¯ using categories developed by Marx in his critique of political economy. In doing so, we return to Marx to help understand the work of academics as productive living labour subsumed by the capitalist mode of production. In elaborating our own position, we are critical of two common approaches to the study of academic labour, especially as they emerge from inside analyses of 'virtual labour' or 'digital work' (Fuchs and Sevignani, 2013; Newfield, 2010; Roggero, 2011).
First, we are critical of efforts to define the nature of our work as ¡®immaterial labour¡¯ (Hardt and Negri, 2000; Peters and Bulut, 2011; Scholtz, 2013) and argue that this category is an unhelpful and unnecessary diversion from the analytical power of Marx¡¯s social theory and method. The discourse around ¡®immaterial labour¡¯ raised by the Autonomist or Operaismo tradition is thought-provoking, but ultimately adds little to a critical theory of commodity production as the basis of capitalist social relations (Postone, 1993; Sohn-Rethel, 1978). In fact they tend to overstate network-centrism and its concomitant disconnection from the hierarchical, globalised forces of production that shape our objective social reality (Robinson, 2004).
Second, we are cautious of an approach which focuses on the digital content of academic labour (Noble, 2002; Weller, 2012) to the neglect of both its form and the organising principles under which it is subsumed (Camfield, 2007). Understandably, academics have a tendency to reify their own labour such that it becomes something that they struggle for, rather than against. However, repeatedly adopting this approach can only lead to a sense of helplessness (Postone, 2006). If, rather, we focus our critique on the form and organising principles of labour, we find that it shares the same general qualities whether it is academic or not. Thus, it is revealed as commodity-producing, with both concrete and abstract forms. By remaining focused on the form of labour, rather than its content, we can only critique it rather than reify it.
This then has implications for our understanding of the relationships between academics and virtual work, the ways in which technologies are used to organise academic labour digitally, and struggles to overcome such labour. It is our approach to conceive of ¡®academic labour¡¯ in both its concrete and abstract forms and in relation to a range of techniques and technologies. The purpose of this is to unite all workers in solidarity against labour (Krisis-Group, 1999), rather than against each other in a competitive labour market.
http://josswinn.org/2014/02/a-contribution-to-the-critique-of-the-political-economy-of-academic-labour/
1 of 10
Download to read offline
More Related Content
A Contribution to the Critique of the Political Economy of Academic Labour
1. A Contribution to the Critique of the Political
Economy of Academic Labour
Prof. Richard Hall, De Montfort, rhall@dmu.ac.uk @hallymk1
Joss Winn, Lincoln, jwinn@lincoln.ac.uk @josswinn
Academic Identities Conference, Durham, 8-9th July 2014
2. English universities today
¡ñ? Increasingly¡
o? Privatised
o? Marketised
o? Financialised
o? Instrumentalised
¡ñ? Regulated by the Department of Business and Innovation
¡ñ? Performance measured by economic ¡®impact¡¯ and ¡®student satisfaction¡¯
¡ñ? They are a means of production (knowledge) and reproduction (labour)
¡ñ? Unproductive labour is being transformed into directly productive
labour through the ¡®real subsumption¡¯ of the university to the capitalist
mode of production
¡ñ? What, now, is the social role of academic labour?
3. ¡®Labour¡¯ as a critical category
¡ñ? Commodity-form (use-value and exchange value)
¡ñ? Dual character of labour expressed in the commodity-form (concrete and
abstract labour)
¡ñ? Labour power (a commodity) is bought for a wage
¡ñ? The wage reflects the value of labour power i.e. the ¡®necessary labour time¡¯
for subsistence
¡ñ? More value can be uniquely produced by labour through extending working
hours or cutting wages = ¡®exploitation¡¯
¡ñ? ¡®Necessary labour time¡¯, ¡®surplus labour time¡¯, ¡®absolute surplus value¡¯,
¡®relative surplus value¡¯.
¡ñ? As productivity of labour increases, the value of labour power decreases
¡ñ? With the increase in the ratio of ¡®dead labour¡¯ over ¡®living labour¡¯, capital
produces a surplus population (precarious, under and unemployed labour)
4. ¡®Immaterial labour¡¯
¡ñ? ¡®Intellectual, affective-emotional and techno-scientific activity¡¯ (Negri and Hardt 1994)
¡ñ? ¡®audio-visual production, advertisement, fashion, software-production, photography,
cultural activities and so on¡¯ (Maurizio Lazzarato, 1993)
¡ñ? The term is used strategically, to unite workers, yet results in confusing abstract labour,
intellectual labour, digital labour, and virtual work. Conflates the labour process with its
product.
¡ñ? ¡°In order to examine the connection between intellectual production and material
production it is above all necessary to grasp the latter itself not as a general category but
in definite historical form. Thus for example different kinds of intellectual production
correspond to the capitalist mode of production and to the mode of production of the
Middle Ages. If material production itself is not conceived in its specific historical form, it is
impossible to understand what is specific in the intellectual production corresponding to it
and the reciprocal influence of one on the other. Otherwise one cannot get beyond
inanities.¡± (Marx, MECW 31, 182)
See Huag (2009) for references and broader critical discussion of this term.
5. ¡®Digital labour¡¯
Alienated and exploited digital work which is defined by its
association with the ICT industry; it creates value for that
industry. It incorporates all physiological aspects of the
human body, its relationship to nature and machines. It is
objectified in digital goods as well as services that are
reliant on digital goods. (Paraphrasing Fuchs 2014)
As such, from ¡®digital slaves¡¯ to ¡®digital scholars¡®, the social form of labour
remains the same, even though the way in which it appears in particular,
concrete case studies, may look quite different.
6. Method: From abstract to concrete
¡°The concrete is concrete because it is the concentration
of many determinations, hence unity of the diverse. It
appears in the process of thinking, therefore, as a process
of concentration, as a result, not as a point of
departure, even though it is the point of departure in reality
and hence also the point of departure for observation and
conception. ¡ the abstract determinations lead towards
a reproduction of the concrete by way of thought.¡± (Marx,
1993, 101)
7. From being to doing
¡ñ? Moten and Harney (1998) argue that we need to view academic
work as an activity rather than a position.
¡ñ? We have a material connection between each other and our
students.
¡ñ? Need to focus on what it means to do academic labour rather than
what it means to be an academic worker.
¡ñ? Must be grounded in a theoretical framework that is adequate to
the task of analysing capitalist social relations.
¡ñ? Need to focus on the university as a means of production for capital
and its exploitation of the divided, social, co-operative labour of
academics and students.
8. Against academic labour
¡ñ? Start from an abstract analysis and move to concrete
¡ñ? Question the social form of academic labour before its
content
¡ñ? It is the activity (doing) of labour which produces
academic identity (being)
¡ñ? Subjectivity in capitalism arises from the imperative to
create value from labour
¡ñ? Hypostasizing labour as ¡®identity¡¯ will lead to a sense of
helplessness and blind resistance
9. References
Fuchs, Christian (2014) Digital Labour and Karl Marx, Routledge.
Haug, W.F. (2009) Immaterial Labour, Historical Materialism 17 (2009) 177¨C
185
Marx, Karl (1976) Capital Volume 1, Penguin Classics.
Marx, Karl (1993) Grundrisse, Penguin Classics.
Moten, Fred and Harney, Stefano (1998) Doing Academic Work, in Martin,
Randy (Ed) Chalk Lines: The politics of work in the managed university,
154-180
See also:
Richard Hall: http://www.richard-hall.org/tag/labour/
Joss Winn: http://josswinn.org/tag/academic-labour/
10. A Contribution to the Critique of the Political Economy
of Academic Labour
Prof. Richard Hall, De Montfort, rhall@dmu.ac.uk @hallymk1
Joss Winn, Lincoln, jwinn@lincoln.ac.uk @josswinn
Academic Identities Conference, Durham, 8-9th July 2014